Government Intervention

Taxation: Addressing Negative Externalities

One common approach governments use to address negative externalities, such as those generated by smoking cigarettes, drinking alcohol, or consuming sugary drinks, is through taxation. By imposing a tax on these goods, governments aim to increase the cost of production, thereby reducing the supply of the good. As the supply decreases, prices increase, and this, in turn, reduces the quantity demanded for the good. The ultimate goal is to lower the consumption of the good to a level that is more socially optimal.


When implementing taxes to address negative externalities, the government should ideally impose a tax equivalent to the Marginal External Costs (MEC) associated with the consumption of the good. However, accurately determining the MEC can be challenging due to information failure. In many cases, it is nearly impossible to correctly estimate the true value of the negative externalities generated.

*Tip: Remember, the key to effective taxation in addressing negative externalities is to set the tax rate at a level equivalent to the Marginal External Costs.

Take the case of cigarette smoking, for example. It is difficult to quantify the exact value of the damage that secondhand smoke causes to third parties. How can we isolate the specific impact of secondhand smoke on an individual's health? How can we calculate the value of this damage? These are challenging questions to answer, and as a result, the valuation of the marginal external costs is often an estimate or an arbitrary value.

Despite these challenges, taxation can still be an effective tool for addressing negative externalities if it is applied in a well-informed and carefully calibrated manner. Governments should invest in research and data collection to better estimate the Marginal External Costs associated with the consumption of goods that generate negative externalities. By doing so, they can more accurately set tax rates and achieve the desired reduction in consumption.

*Tip: Accurate estimation of Marginal External Costs is crucial for effective taxation policies. Governments should invest in research and data collection to improve their understanding of the social costs associated with the consumption of goods that generate negative externalities.

Plastic Bag Charge in Singapore - How the Singapore government uses salience bias as a nudge in influencing consumers’ behaviour

In some instances, governments may opt for alternative interventions that function similarly to taxes in addressing negative externalities. One such example can be found in Singapore, where the government implemented a "minimum 5 cents charge" for plastic bags at supermarkets.

Although this policy is not strictly considered a tax, as the government does not collect the charge, it still requires supermarkets to adopt a minimum charge for plastic bags. The policy aims to reduce the consumption of plastic bags by shifting the supply (or the Marginal Private Cost curve) to the left. However, when considering that a 5 cent charge on groceries valued at $10 is less than 1% of the total cost, the policy may appear to be relatively ineffective.

*Tip: Be aware that governments may use alternative interventions, like minimum charges, that function similarly to taxes in addressing negative externalities.

So, what is the Singapore government trying to achieve with this policy? The answer lies in the government's use of salience bias to nudge consumers towards adopting the desired behavior. By implementing a 5 cent charge for plastic bags, the government is not necessarily trying to make it financially 'painful' for consumers to use plastic bags. Instead, the policy aims to make the environmental cost of plastic bags more salient each time a consumer makes a grocery purchase, prompting the question: "Do I need the plastic bag?"

This approach demonstrates how governments can harness cognitive biases, such as salience bias, to nudge economic agents towards more environmentally friendly choices. Even if the charge is relatively small, the act of having to consider whether a plastic bag is necessary can lead to more mindful consumption and, ultimately, reduced plastic bag usage.

*Tip: Governments can leverage cognitive biases, like salience bias, to nudge economic agents towards more sustainable behaviors.

In conclusion, the Singapore government's "minimum 5 cents charge" policy for plastic bags is an interesting example of how alternative interventions can address negative externalities. By leveraging salience bias, the government encourages consumers to think twice about their need for plastic bags, ultimately promoting more sustainable consumption habits.


Subsidies: Addressing Positive Externalities

In markets where significant external benefits can be derived, governments often opt to provide subsidies to support the production of the good in question. Subsidies have the effect of reducing the cost of production, which in turn increases the supply of the good. As supply increases, prices decrease, leading to a higher quantity demanded for the good. This increased consumption results in a more socially optimal outcome, as the positive externalities are better realized.

It is essential to note that the objective of subsidies is to achieve a more socially optimal level of consumption, not necessarily the perfect equilibrium. To address the problem of positive externalities effectively, the government should provide a subsidy equivalent to the Marginal External Benefits (MEB). However, accurately estimating the true value of positive externalities can be challenging, especially due potential information failure on the government’s part.

Consider the case of vaccinations: How can we assign a value to the benefits that third parties receive from herd immunity? What methods can we use to calculate the probability of one person being less likely to catch a disease due to increased vaccination rates within the population? These are difficult questions to answer, and any valuation of the marginal external benefits will likely be an estimate or an arbitrary value.

Moreover, it's essential to consider the implications of subsidies on government resources and budget positions. Subsidies can be a drain on government finances, leading to questions about whether there are more efficient ways to allocate funds. This highlights the importance of carefully evaluating the cost-effectiveness of subsidies in addressing positive externalities.

*Tip: Always consider the potential inefficiencies of subsidies, such as their impact on government budgets and whether there are more cost-effective alternatives.

Incorporating Different Levels of Subsidies: The Case of Singapore's Education System

When determining the appropriate level of subsidies, economic theory suggests that the amount should be equivalent to the Marginal External Benefits (MEB). However, in real-world situations, governments may adopt different subsidy levels depending on the good or service in question. For instance, let's examine the case of Singapore's education system.

In Singapore, citizens pay $0 for primary education, $5 for secondary education, and $6 for pre-university education per month. These fees represent a more than 99% subsidy for students at these educational levels.

As an economics student, you can analyze this situation using the positive externalities diagram. To understand the reasoning behind these different subsidy levels, consider the distance between the Marginal Private Benefits (MPB) and Marginal Social Benefits (MSB) curves.

*Tip: When analyzing subsidies using the positive externalities diagram, focus on the distance between the MPB and MSB curves.

In the case of primary, secondary, and pre-university education, the distance between the MPB and MSB curves might be significant, implying that the positive externalities generated by these levels of education are substantial. The government recognizes these considerable benefits and provides high subsidies to encourage greater consumption of these educational services.

On the other hand, the distance between the MPB and MSB curves might be smaller for university education, suggesting that the positive externalities generated by university education are relatively lower compared to earlier educational stages. As a result, the Singapore government may choose to provide a lower subsidy level of around 75% for university education.

In conclusion, the differences in subsidy levels for various stages of Singapore's education system can be explained using the positive externalities diagram by considering the distance between the MPB and MSB curves. By providing subsidies in line with the perceived positive externalities, the government aims to achieve more socially optimal consumption levels of education at each stage.


Did you know that Government Interventions is commonly tested in the A-Level as an Essay? Are you confident that you can tackle them? If you aren’t, we are here to help:

The 2024 ETG June Holiday Intensive Crashcourse is your key to exam success.

What we offer:

  • Covering 8 crucial macroeconomics & microeconomics topics which are commonly tested in A Levels

  • Master a Massive Arsenal of Questions: We'll expose you to a wider variety of exam-style questions than you've ever seen.

  • Double the Practice, Double the Confidence: In just two intensive days, you'll tackle more essays and case studies than you probably have all year!

  • Unlock High-Scoring Answers: Learn the secrets to crafting top-notch evaluations that will impress examiners.

  • Structure Like a Pro: We'll equip you with the skills to dissect questions and write clear, well-structured essay responses.

This Crashcourse is the ultimate shortcut to A-Level Economics domination! Don't miss out - secure your spot today! Register for our Content Crashcourses and Essay & Case Study Bootcamp here!


Take a look at our stunningly curated textbooks, exclusively available for ETG students only:

Curious to find out about the ETG experience? Register for a Trial Lesson now! (P.S. There are free gifts when you join our Trial Lessons)